Tideman alternative method

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Tideman's Alternative Method, also called Alternative Smith or Alternative Schwartz, is an electoral system developed by Nicolaus Tideman which selects a single winner using votes that express preferences.

This method is Smith-efficient, making it a kind of Condorcet method. It uses instant-runoff voting for cycle resolution.

Procedure[edit]

Tideman's Alternative Smith with three in the Smith set

The Alternative Smith procedure is as follows:

  1. Eliminate all candidates outside the Smith set.
  2. If there is more than one candidate remaining, eliminate the last-place candidate as in IRV.
  3. Repeat the procedure until there is only one candidate left.

Features[edit]

Strategy-resistance[edit]

Alternative Smith strongly resists both strategic nomination and strategic voting by political parties or coalitions (although like every system, it can still be manipulated in some situations). The Smith and runoff components of Smith-runoff cover up each other's weaknesses:

  1. Smith-efficient methods are difficult for any coalition to manipulate, because no majority-strength coalition will have an incentive to remove a Condorcet winner: if most voters prefer A to B, A can already defeat B.
    • This reasoning does not apply to situations with a Condorcet cycle, however.
    • While Condorcet cycles are rare in practice with honest voters, burial (ranking a strong rival last, below weak opponents) can often create a false cycle.
  2. Instant runoff voting is resistant to burial, because it is only based on each voter's top preference in any given round. This means that burial strategies effective against the Smith-elimination step are not effective against the instant runoff step.
    • On the other hand, instant-runoff voting is highly vulnerable to a lesser evil (decapitation) strategy: defeating a greater evil requires voters to rank a strong candidate first, rather than express their sincere beliefs.
    • However, if such a candidate exists (with majority support), they will usually be a Condorcet winner, and elected in the first round.

The combination of these two methods creates a highly-resistant system.

Spoiler effects[edit]

Alternative Smith fails independence of irrelevant alternatives, meaning it can sometimes be affected by spoiler candidates. However, the method adheres to a weaker property that eliminates most spoilers, sometimes called independence of Smith-dominated alternatives (ISDA). This method states that if one candidate (X) wins an election, and a new alternative (Y) is added, X will still win the election as long as Y is not in the highest-ranked cycle.

Comparison table[edit]

The following table compares Alternative Smith with other single-winner election methods:

Comparison of voting systems
Criterion: Majority Majority loser criterion Mutual majority criterion Condorcet winner[Tn 1] Condorcet loser Smith[Tn 1] ISDA[Tn 1] LIIA IIA[Tn 1] Cloneproof Monotone Participation Reversal Later-no-harm[Tn 1] Later-no-help[Tn 1] No favorite betrayal[Tn 1]
Anti-plurality No Yes No No No No No No No No Yes Yes No No No Yes
Approval Yes No No No[Tn 2] No Yes Yes Yes Yes[Tn 3] Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes
Baldwin Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No No No No No
Black Yes Yes No Yes Yes No No No No No Yes No Yes No No No
Borda count No Yes No No Yes No No No No No Yes Yes Yes No Yes No
Bucklin Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No No Yes No No No Yes No
Coombs Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No No No No No No No No Yes
Copeland Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No Yes No Yes No No No
Dodgson Yes No No Yes No No No No No No No No No No No No
Instant-runoff voting Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No No Yes No No No Yes Yes No
Kemeny–Young Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No Yes No Yes No No No
Minimax Yes No No Yes No No No No No No Yes No No No No No
Nanson Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No Yes No No No
Plurality Yes No No No No No No No No No Yes Yes No Yes Yes No
Ranked pairs Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes No Yes No No No
Schulze Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No Yes Yes No Yes No No No
Tideman alternative Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No Yes No No No No No No

Table notes[edit]

  1. ^ a b c d e f g |Condorcet, Smith and Independence of Smith-dominated alternatives criteria are incompatible with Independence of irrelevant alternatives, Consistency, Participation, Later-no-harm, Later-no-help, and Favorite betrayal[clarification needed] criteria.
  2. ^ In Approval, Range, and Majority Judgment, if all voters have perfect information about each other's true preferences and use rational strategy, any Majority Condorcet or Majority winner will be strategically forced – that is, win in all of one or more strong Nash equilibria. In particular if every voter knows that "A or B are the two most-likely to win" and places their "approval threshold" between the two, then the Condorcet winner, if one exists and is in the set {A,B}, will always win. These methods also satisfy the majority criterion in the weaker sense that any majority can force their candidate to win, if it so desires. Laslier, J-F (2006), "Strategic approval voting in a large electorate" (PDF), IDEP Working Papers (405), Marseille, France
  3. ^ Approval voting, range voting, and majority judgment satisfy IIA if it is assumed that voters rate candidates individually and independently of knowing the available alternatives in the election, using their own absolute scale. For this to hold, in some elections, some voters must use less than their full voting power or even abstain, despite having meaningful preferences among the available alternatives. If this assumption is not made, these methods fail IIA, as they become more ranked than rated methods.


References[edit]